Economic theory and practice tells us that economies of scale have the
potential to increase welfare of both consumer and manufacturer. However, there
are limits to the advantages that they can bring.
It is important to be aware of
some of these. Changes in market demand, linked to large units of capital
equipment have the potential to produce high levels of output – but if demand
is at a low level, capital will be under-utilised leading to excess capacity
and rising average total costs.
Some large units of capital may
not be transferable to other uses if there is a switch in consumer demand due
either to sufficient lack of demand in other areas or operational restrictions.
This is clearly applicable to the container shipping market and the potential
for shifting fortunes in the market.
Diseconomies of scale may appear when the units of production, the very
large containerships, grow beyond the scale of production that minimises long-run
average cost. The rise in the long run average cost is caused by diseconomies
of scale. It is often difficult to pinpoint exactly the causes of diseconomies
of scale, however management theorists often point to issues related to control
of the productive units and the coordination along a large supply chain that
needs to fill a ship of 12,000 teu every week.
Let us consider an example of the 10,000
teu-12,000 teu ships, all coming on stream during a period of unprecedented
trade growth, we need to consider the above economic theories. Let’s consider
the Europe-Asia trade where the demand and volumes are sufficiently large to
sustain these ships.
A string of eight ships sailing
at around 24.5 knots with a minimal number of port calls, however the same
string travelling at 21.5 knots would
require around 40%- 50% less bunkers. Alternatively, more ports of call would
need an additional vessel, at a cost of $165m, around $50,000 per day,plus the
extra fuel costs.
The question is, at what point does the equilibrium between additional
fuel costs and asset cost break, causing a shift in the slope of economies of
scale. Have we reached this point of diminishing returns?
Let us look at the bigger picture – a more holistic view
Like other forms of
transportation, container shipping benefits from economies of scale in maritime
shipping, transshipment and inland transportation. The rationale of maritime
container shipping companies to have larger ships becomes obvious when the
benefits, in terms of lower costs per TEU, increase with the capacity of ships.
There is thus a powerful trend to increase the size of ships, but this may lead
to diseconomies to other components of container shipping.
For port terminals the growth in
ship capacity comes with increasing problems to cope with large amounts of
containers to be transshipped over short periods of time as shipping companies
want to reduce their port time as much as possible (improved ship asset utilization
and keeping up with schedule integrity). Larger cranes and larger quantities of
land for container operations, namely temporary warehousing on container yards,
may become prohibitive, triggering diseconomies of scale to be assumed by port
authorities and terminal operators.
For inland transportation
congestion growing capacity, such as more trucks converging towards terminal
gates, leads to diseconomies. Because of technical innovations and functional
changes in inland transportation, such as using rail instead of trucking to
move containers from or to terminals, it is unclear what is the effective
capacity beyond which diseconomies of scale are achieved.
The fundamental point is that diseconomies are a challenge that impacts
several segments of the transport chain.
Source: Hostra Edu
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.